Laserfiche WebLink
' �►��! s ��11 <br />The Clawback Cla use <br />our years ago, Georgia made a tax-subsidy deal with <br />Alltel Corp., a telecommunications company based in <br />Little Rock. Under Georgia's "revenue and apportion- <br />ment" program, Alltel received tax breaks totaling <br />$13.5 million over five years-one of six companies <br />(along with Turner Broadcasting, HBO, General Electric and <br />others) to receive such benefits. <br />Even at that price, it would have been a good deal for Georgia. <br />The agreement called for the company to produce almost 800 <br />new jobs at its Alpharetta, Georgia, headquarters. That's about <br />$17,000 per job, but Alltel promised the jobs would pay on aver- <br />age more than $60,000 per year. <br />Last spring, however, Alltel acknowledged that it hadn't met <br />the terms of the deal. After instituting company-wide cutbacks <br />in 2001, the company wound up with about 135 more jobs in <br />Georgia than it had in 1998, according to one estimate. And <br />there was no evidence that the jobs paid anywhere near $60,000 <br />per year. <br />Was Alltel simply responding to economic downturns by cut- <br />ting back on its expansion plans and consolidating Southern <br />operations in Florida rather than Georgia? Or did Georgia get <br />taken by a company that accepted tax breaks and turned a <br />healthy profit while welching on its end of the deal? <br />Either way, Georgia might be able to get some of its $13.5 mil- <br />lion back-if it chooses to pursue Alltel under the "clawback" <br />provisions contained in the state's tax-subsidy law. The law isn't <br />airtight; Georgia doesn't even get a compliance report from the <br />company unless state officials ask for one. <br />The state may or may not pursue a settlement. But the Alltel <br />case is the latest example of an emerging question in economic <br />development If a company getting tax breaks doesn't deliver <br />the goods, should the government agency involved demand its <br />money back? <br />Clawback provisions-the term is taken from tax law-are <br />increasingly common and some givebacks are taking place. <br />' <br />WILLIAM FULTON <br />norm. By and large, the corporate-tax subsidy is still viewed as a <br />one-way street in the United States. <br />On the surface, it makes sense to insist on a clawback But <br />whether it's realistic depends on how you view the true nature <br />of a tax subsidy. It can be seen as a loan to a company: a finan- <br />cial liability that must be paid back if things don't pan ouc Or it <br />can be considered an investment: a financial bet by the govern- <br />ment that the company will grow and prosper. <br />There's an argument both ways here. On the one hand, we're <br />talking about tax money. It's <br />O.K. to put that money at risk <br />for a valid public policy ObJeC• <br />tive such as economic develop- <br />ment. But it's not a whole lot <br />diffeient than an economic <br />development agency providing <br />a below-market loan to a grow- <br />ing company-a risky process, <br />to be sure, but one. in which <br />financial recourse is part of the <br />deaL The agency loaning the <br />money may lose it in the end if <br />�'� �� the company tanks, but it <br />might get at least part of it back <br />"' ` as creditors are paid off. <br />On the other hand, there's no way to guarantee the success <br />of a business venture-that the markets will be there far the <br />products and services and that contracts will continue to flow <br />in. Given the recent history of corporate America, there isn't <br />even any way to be sure that a large company will be managed <br />well-or even honestly. <br />To take the argument a little further: It's one thing for eco- <br />nomic developers to lay the necessary groundwork for prosper- <br />ity-to provide significant pieces of economic infrastructure (air- <br />ports, highways, buildings) or to try to stimulate specific parts of <br />the economy (by encouraging netwarking <br />among industrial clusters and the like). It's <br />another thing, however, to lay a bet on a spe- <br />deliver the goods, should the state or cific company. That's not economic develop- <br />ment. That's gambling. <br />locality involved demand its money back? claW�a�kpro��s�ons m�ght a�ter the ba�- <br />If a company getting tax breaks doesn't <br />United Airlines returned more than $30 million to government <br />agencies in Indiana last year after failing to meet its jobs goal for <br />a maintenance hub at Indianapolis International Airport-a deal <br />that gave the airline $300 million in tax breaks. After he was <br />elected mayor of New York City, Michael Bloomberg rescinded a <br />tax-break deal his company had negotiated with the city. (It was <br />a refund steeped in irony: The subsidy was less than the sum he <br />spent on his campaign.) <br />Nonetheless, enforcing clawback provisions still isn't the <br />ance of power to some extent. They could, <br />for example, put corporate executives on alert that the govern- <br />ment is interested in a partnership, not in giving away money. <br />The clauses could also have no effect whatsoever. The Com- <br />petitive pressures in American economic development-state <br />against state, city against city-make it unlikely that clawbacks <br />will become the norm rather than the exception. So let's be clear <br />about whaYs going on. If the taxpayers want to lay a bet on a spe- � <br />cifiC company, they can't complain about what happens to their � <br />money in a bear market. �� <br />72 G 0 V E R N I N G October 2002 � Governing.com <br />